What is globalization?

 

Anyone who follows the news with even cursory interest has witnessed fierce arguments regarding something called “globalization.” Among the highlights, we see that protesters in Seattle have rioted against it, that the G8 meets to guide its progress, and that the WTO is supposed to preside over its execution. But even the perceptive reader must be forgiven if, upon request, he is unable to provide a concise definition of “globalization.” For from its beginnings in 1980’s analysis of perestroika and détente, the term has grown in importance, and now encompasses a system that has partially supplanted the pre-21st century mode of international relations.1

Ignacio Ramonet provides an ideal entry-point for a discussion of globalization with his insightful remark that globalization “imposes the force of two powerful and contradictory dynamics on the world: fusion and fission.”2 The side of this dichotomy most often discussed is the integrative side, which seems to be the prime and explicit connotation of the term “globalization.” With the collapse of the great divisions of the Cold War, the relatively staid network of inter-state alliances has been replaced by a new discourse that emphasizes market values above ]all others. Under this new, economically-driven political system, barriers to free trade between different countries are seen as impediments to the ever-increasing efficiency of the economy, and therefore must be eliminated for the sake of economic growth. 3 The world’s developed nations have become gigantic investors in each others’ markets, allocating and exchanging capital, labor, and knowledge over great distances with fluid agility. Nor do the less developed countries (LDCs) miss out on the fruits of free trade; with their previously-untapped labor forces, these countries can make huge gains through exports. In fact, the information revolution has allowed these countries to export services as well as goods, as seen by the rapidly-proliferating call centers in many of these nations. All the countries of the world are drawn tightly together in a bewildering web of economic relationships that benefit everyone.

Beneath this shimmering veneer of everybody-wins capitalism, however, lie fractured remnants of the casualties of the inexorably increasing competitiveness in this new global era. This is the other side of globalization, governed by its divisive aspect. In some cases, it acts on those unwilling or unable to comply with its mandate of unification. Ramonet, in the same article as mentioned above, gives the example of the 3 Warsaw pact nations of Czechoslovakia, Yugoslavia, and the USSR. In the new era of globalization, these have shattered into 22 nations, many of them badly rived by ethnic and cultural strife.4 Aside from these overt cases of the consequences of globalization, however, it is easily observed that even the developed countries are somewhat disingenuous in declaring their dedication to untrammeled international commerce. The nation-state is still the supreme actor in the world, and every state is still quietly willing to implement protectionist measures as long as its allies do not protest too loudly. The fact that the European Union and United States grant around $300B per year in agricultural subsidies is illustrative of this state-centric selfishness; it is also worth noting, along the lines of selfishness, that this is roughly six times the amount that these richest countries spend on aid. 5 This last figure suggests that globalization might not be equally focused on all human wellbeing, and indeed by many accounts globalization has done nothing to stop the widening of one of the greatest gaps of all, that between the rich and the poor.6

Given the respective normative values afforded by these mutually opposed sides of globalization, it is unsurprising that those who support or oppose globalization tend to emphasize one side rather than the other. While my analysis of their positions will unfold along those lines, it is important to note that both the integrative and divisive aspects of globalization are manifestations of a single entity, and to analyze either in the absence of its larger context is to miss the point. Never the less, there are good points to be made by each side.

 

Arguments for globalization

 

Given that globalization is the engine that fuels the intense economic growth of the developed world, it goes without saying that its supporters should be many and extremely powerful. With few exceptions, these include not just the governments of the G8 and other developed nations, but also the governments of the LDCs. These governments have committed themselves to the pursuit of globalization by signing the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), empowering the WTO to enforce free trade, even to the point of sanctioning member nations for violations.

This clear hegemony of globalization stems from the fact that globalization itself is a natural consequence of the modern economical framework.7 The preponderance of current economic thought supports the central proposition of globalization: that free-trade is essential for the maximization of economic efficiency and growth. The marriage of globalization to this extraordinarily powerful social science has proved to be among its most useful assets, and the most forceful arguments for globalization are those that deal with economics.

As for this free-trade principle, there appears to be a good deal of evidence to support it. Most economists agree that poverty is linked to growth; on average, for every 1 point of real GDP contraction, poverty increases by 2 points.8 A large study of nearly 200 countries from 1961 to 1999 revealed that the majority of countries which showed high growth had governments dedicated to free trade, whereas most of those countries in which the economies shrank (especially those with severe contractions) had implemented protectionist policies.9 Other proponents of globalization add that those countries that earliest entered the global market have had the highest growth. And, according to the World Bank, the 1990’s saw the first-ever reduction in gross poverty, from 1.2B to 1.1B people.10 Finally, there is the spectacular example of the East Asian countries, which have exploited knowledge capital via globalization to achieve astonishing export-driven growth rates. In summary, free trade creates growth, uplifting those in poverty and uniting them with the developed world in joint prosperity.

It must be said that the vast majority of the arguments in favor of globalization rely on the causal relationships from free trade to growth and growth to poverty-reduction. Perhaps the deep reverence in which this principle is held, coupled with the already rapid spread of globalization, has caused an exuberant spirit among its proponents and eliminated many potential seeds of doubt. And while the general truth of that principle is difficult to dispute, there are those who question the practice of applying it unconditionally to all economies worldwide.

 

Arguments against globalization

 

Since most economists are supporters of the spread of globalization, the popular opposition to globalization is based mainly on social and moral grounds. Some opponents are governments of LDCs that perceive globalization as impinging upon their sovereignty, and others are NGOs or aid groups that deplore the humanitarian consequences of globalization. Yet there is a small, but vocal minority of economists who challenge even the economic basis for globalization.

The primary problem these economists see in globalization is the serious failure of large investors to tailor their economic approach to the country at hand. These investors include the IMF, World Bank and the U.S. Treasury, both of which are unflinchingly devoted to the free-market concept. The typical (and oft-repeated) scenario is that an LDC seeks out loans from the IMF or U.S. Treasury to develop the infrastructure required to join the global market. As a condition of these loans, these lenders impose stringent conditions on the borrowing country’s budget. Frequently, the borrowing country is ordered to cut social programs to service its debt, or to eliminate controls on the market; both of these conditions can be disastrous, leading to an ongoing dependence of the borrowing country on foreign aid.11 A country cannot successfully join the global economy if it is hamstrung by unreasonable external controls.

Another problem with globalization as implemented by the Northern hegemony is that it is inherently designed to serve the interests of the North. As an example, a World Bank analysis of the effects of the 1994 Uruguay talks showed that the United States and Europe were extremely well off, but sub-Sarharan Africa actually lost 3%. Part of the reason for this is that while LDCs are forced to open their doors to the imports of the developed countries of the North, the latter countries use unfair “anti-flooding” laws or specious health or safety standards to block much of the LDCs’ exports from ever reaching markets. 12

A few economists even debate the veracity of most claims for the success of globalization. Nowhere is the divisive influence of globalization better seen, they argue, than in this sobering statistic: in 1980, the median income of the top decile of wealthy countries was 77 times that of the bottom decile, but in 1999 this disparity had grown to 122 times. Also, much of the supposed growth and alleviation of poverty in LDCs can be accounted for by the inclusion of China’s per capita GDP, a misleading statistic given the greatly increasing inequality in that country.13

 

Conclusion

 

In presenting the two sides of globalization I have remained mostly within the realm of economics to explain globalization and its attendant phenomena. But there are, as I mentioned earlier, serious moral and social problems with today’s globalization that compel me to view it with deep skepticism. Part of what repels me is the North’s seemingly boundless arrogance in suggesting to LDCs that it, rather than they, should control their economies. This idea is not only antidemocratic, but inimical to the very core of what free trade ought to represent.14 More disturbingly, the North’s implementation of globalization smacks of imperialism.

To illustrate this point, I make reference to Johan Galtung’s structural theory of imperialism. In this framework, the more developed country is divided into an elite center, and the less-empowered periphery. Since the goal of the center is to increase its dominion over the periphery, and the goal of the periphery to resist this encroachment, there is some amount of disunity within this developed country. Then, however, the center of this developed country takes an interest in an LDC. By transacting with a certain class within that LDC, the center of the developed nation elevates that class to center status within the LDC. To cement its newfound domination by pleasing its master, this center of the LDC (which is proportionally much smaller than the center of the developed nation, due to the developed nation’s republican government) aids the center of the developed nation in striping away the resources of the periphery of the LDC and passing them to the center of the developed nation, which uses the resources in its own quest for supremacy. One would hope that perhaps the peripheries of the two nations would realize their similar plight and rise up to end this unfortunate situation, but since the periphery of the developed nation is culturally closer to the center of its own nation than to the LDC, the exploitative relationship continues unabated.15

This theory of globalization extends effortlessly from the original theory of imperialism, and goes precisely to the heart of Ramonet’s dichotomy: productive unification does occur, but only for the elites of the countries involved. Far more serious are the consequences for the lower classes everywhere, who, as a result of the increasing power of the elites, are ever more-distant from parity.

This is not to say that globalization should be avoided at all costs. On the contrary, a democratization of world trade can and does have many beneficial effects. What is needed, however, is a system of globalization that is equitable and benefits LDCs as much – or even more – than developed nations. Only then will globalization truly achieve what it professes.



1 “Dueling globalizations: A debate between Thomas L. Friedman and Ignacio Ramonet” Foreign Policy, Fall 1999 issue 116, p110 This idea is Friedman’s

2 Ibid.

3 Gill, Stephen. “Constitutionalizing Inequality and the Clash of globalizations”, International Studies Review; Summer 2002, Vol. 4 Issue 2, p47

4 Friedman and Ramonet, 2002

5 Birdsall, Nancy. “Cheerleaders, cynics, and worried doubters”. Global Agenda, Jan 2003 Issue 1. p32

6 Hersh, Adam, and Weller, Christian E., “Free Markets and Poverty,”. The American Prospect, Volume 13 Issue 1. January 1-14 2002.

7 Gill 2002

8 Hersh and Weller, 2002

9  Panagariya, Arvind, as cited in Bhagwati, Jagdish, “The Human Face of globalization.”  Global Agenda, Jan 2004 Issue 2, p74

10 Birdsall 2003.

11 Stiglitz, Joseph E., “Globalism’s Discontents.” American Prospect, Volume 13, Issue 1. January 1-14 2002.

12 Ibid.

13 Hersh and Weller, 2002.

14 Stiglitz, 2002.

15 Galtung, Johan. “A Structural Theory of Imperialism”, Journal of Peace Research 8: 81-117, 1971. reprinted in “Approaches to Peace,” 2000, ed. Barash, David P.